Antitrust is the new economy- Richard A. Posner
Way back in 19th century there were several big giant businesses which were
known as
trusts. These trusts used to control the whole section of the economy
like railroads, sugar, coal, steel etc. Two of the most famous trusts at that
time were the U.S. Steel and Standard Oil.
They were monopolies which controlled
the supply of their products to maintain the price. The trust first appeared in
US railroads where the capital requirement of railroad construction precluded
competition services in then scarcely settled territories. This trust allowed
the railroads to discriminate on rates imposed and services provided to
consumers and businesses and to destroy the potential competitor.[i]
Due to the
formation of these controlled several markets, the vast number of citizens
become sufficiently aware and publicly concerned about the negative impact of
these trusts. So, between 1888 and 1890, thirteen states and the federal
government enacted antitrust legislation criminalizing combinations among
competitors intended to control the prices in the marketplace.[ii]
In 1898, Then President of United States William McKinley launched the
trust-busting era when he appointed several senators to the U.S. Industrial
Commission. Later, the Industrial Commission's report to President Theodore
Roosevelt laid the foundation for attacks on trusts and
malefactors of great wealth.[iii]
The Sherman Act[iv] is the United States' oldest antitrust law. It was passed in
1890. It made it illegal for the competitors to make an agreement with each
other that would limit competition for them.
This Act also made it illegal for a
business to be a monopoly if the company is cheating or not competing fairly. In
1914, the Clayton Act was passed to further tap on the antitrust practices such
as merger to control the prices and production. The Clayton Act tried to protect
the consumers by stopping mergers or acquisitions that are likely to stifle
competition.
Along with the Clayton Act, the Congress also created a new federal
agency to watch out for unfair business practices and gave Federal Trade
Commission the authority to investigate and stop unfair methods of competition
and deceptive practices by enacting Federal Trade Commission (FTC) Act. Today
FTC's Bureau of Competition and Department of Justice's Antitrust Division
enforces these three-core federal antitrust laws.[v]
However, the approach towards the antitrust law in united states and the whole
world has seen a major shift from initially being an approach that checks the
economic structure to approach which is now more concerned about the consumer
welfare. The latter approach was brought and popularized by the Chicago school.
Structural Based Approach Of Antitrust Law:
The approach of economic structuralism was based on the idea that concentrated
market structures promote anti-competitive forms of conduct.[vi] It was of the
view that a market which is dominated by a small number of large companies is
likely to be less competitive than a large number of small- and medium-sized
companies.
This was basically due to two reasons:
- monopolistic and oligopolistic market structure enables the dominant
actor to better co-ordinate and easily facilitate anti-competitive practices
like price-fixing, market division, and tacit collusion;
- Monopolistic and oligopolistic market always acts as a roadblock for new
market entrant;
- Consumer loses the bargaining power which enables the monopolistic
market players to hike prices and degrade service and quality while
maintaining profits.
This understanding was the foundation of antitrust policy and thoughts
throughout the 1960s. Courts in the United States subscribing to these views
started to block mergers which would have eventually led to the anticompetitive
practice in the market. In some instances, the Hon'ble Courts also started to
block the horizontal mergers as well as the vertical mergers. Horizontal mergers
were those where the two directly competing market players would merger to form
a single large entity to enjoy a larger share in the market.
On the other hand,
the vertical mergers were those where companies that were operating at different
tiers of the supply or production chain would merger to
foreclose competition.[vii] The main concern of this approach was not just the size but
also the conflict of the interest- like whether allowing a dominant shoe
manufacturer to extend into shoe retailing would create an incentive for the
manufacturer to disadvantage or discriminate against competing retailers.[viii]
Structural Based Approach Of Antitrust Law:
During the 1970s and 1980s, a new approach gained momentum which was called the
Chicago School Approach. They completely rejected the view of a structuralist.
In the words of Richard Posner, the essence of the Chicago School lies in
viewing the antitrust problems through the lens of Price Theory.[ix]
The
foundation of this view was the belief in the efficiency of markets, propelled
by profit-maximizing actors. Economics actors that are working within the market
seek to maximize profits by combining inputs most efficiently. A failure to act
in this will lead to punishment by the competitive forces of the market.[x]
Economic structuralists believed that industrial structure predisposes firms to
act towards a certain kind of behaviour that would then steer the market
outcome. While the Chicago School presumed that the market outcomes like firm
size, industry structure, and concentration levels reflect the interplay between
the standalone market forces and technical demands of production.[xi]
Problem From The Shift:
The first major problem from this shift was the significant narrowing of the
concept of entry barriers. The entry barrier is the initial cost that every firm
needs to bear who seeks entry in the industry but this cost is not carried by
the firms already established in the industry. Advantages like capital
requirements and scales don't reflect entry barrier according to Chicago School
as according to them these are just objective technical demands of production
and distribution.[xii] It considered that regardless of the size and the levels
of concentration all firms have a threat of potential competition. Hence the
market powers are always short-lived.
The second major consequence from the shift was that consumer prices became the
dominant metric for assessing competition. Even Robert Bork, the former
Solicitor General in the Reagan administration in his book Antitrust Paradox
asserted that the sole normative objective of antitrust should be to maximize
consumer welfare, which is best pursued by increasing the economic efficiency.
IN 1979, the Supreme Court started following Bork's work and declared that:
Congress designed the Sherman Act as a consumer welfare prescription.[xiii]
With the coming of the Reagan Administration, there was a radical departure from
the guidelines of 1968 which established that the primary goal of the merger
enforcement was to preserve and promote market structures conducive to competition.[xiv] While the 1982 guidelines mentioned that the mergers should
not be permitted to create or enhance market power', where market power was
defined as the
ability of one or more firms profitably to maintain prices above
competitive levels.[xv]
Conclusion:
Nowadays, showing antitrust injury requires that one has to show harm to
consumer welfare generally in the form of price increases and output
restrictions. Though it is also true that the antitrust authorities have not
entirely ignored non-price effects.
For example, the 2010 Horizontal Merger
Guidelines acknowledged that enhanced market power can manifest non-price harms.[xvi] Even Obama Administration also had opposition to the largest mergers
on its watch -Comcast/TimeWarner based on the concerns about the market access
but not the prices.[xvii]
But it is still correct to say that the concern for
non-price effects rarely animates or drives investigations or enforcement actions.[xviii] Economic factors that are easier to measure such as the impact
of price, output or productive efficiency have become disproportionately important.[xix]
End-Notes:
- Competition law - Wikipedia, , https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Competition_law
(last visited Jun 10, 2020
- Collins, W.D., 2012. Trusts and the origins of antitrust legislation.
Fordham L. Rev., 81, p.2279.
- Presidents of the United States - President William McKinley - TheUSAonline.com, , https://www.theusaonline.com/presidents/william-mckinley.htm
(last visited Jun 11, 2020).
- Our Documents - Transcript of Sherman Anti-Trust Act (1890), , https://www.ourdocuments.gov/doc.php?flash=false&doc=51&page=transcript
(last visited Jun 11, 2020).
- (No Title), , https://www.consumer.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/games/off-site/youarehere/pages/pdf/FTC-Competition_Antitrust-Laws.pdf
(last visited Jun 11, 2020).
- Horace M Gray, CARL KAYSEN and DONALD F. TURNER. Antitrust Policy: An
Economic and Legal Analysis. Pp. xxiii, 345. Cam bridge, Mass.: Harvard
University Press, 1959. \$7.50, 330 Ann. Am. Acad. Pol. Soc. Sci. 199 (1960),
https://doi.org/10.1177/000271626033000183.
- Brown Shoe Co., Inc. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294 (1962)
- Id.
- Richard A Posner, The Chicago School of antitrust analysis, 127 Univ.
PA. Law Rev. 925–948 (1979)
- Marc Allen Eisner, Antitrust and the triumph of economics: institutions,
expertise, and policy change (1991).
- Paul H Brietzke, Robert Bork, The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with
Itself, 13 Valparaiso Univ. Law Rev. 403–421 (2011).
- Marc Allen Eisner, Antitrust and the triumph of economics: institutions,
expertise, and policy change (1991).
- Reiter v. Sonotone Corp., 442 U.S. 330, 343 (1979)
- 1968 Merger Guidelines, U.S. DEP'T JUST. 1 (1968), http://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files
/atr/legacy/2007/07/11/11247.pdf
- 1982 Merger Guidelines, U.S. DEP'T JUST. 2 (1982), http://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files
/atr/legacy/2007/07/11/11248.pdf
- Horizontal Merger Guidelines, U.S. DEP'T JUST. & FTC (Aug. 19, 2010),
http://www.ftc.gov /sites/default/files/attachments/merger-review/100819hmg.pdf
- Emily Steel, Under Regulators' Scrutiny, Comcast and Time Warner Cable
End Deal, N.Y. TIMES (Apr. 24, 2015), http://www.nytimes.com/2015/04/25/business/media/comcast
-time-warner-cable-deal.html
- Marcin Mleczko, Maurice E. Stucke, Allen P. Grunes, Big Data and
Competition Policy, Oxford University Press, 2016, ss. 368, 7 internetowy Kwart.
Antymonop. i Regul. 163–165 (2018).
- Id.
Please Drop Your Comments